• The longest ever study of consumer-directed health plans, ctd.

    Paul Fronstin and Christopher Roebuck (PDF) have a follow-up to their consumer-directed health plan (CDHP) paper with Martín Sepúlveda, about which I wrote last month. I read that prior work as simultaneously encouraging for CDHPs (suggesting lower outpatient visits and prescription drug use without long-term reduction in preventative screening) and discouraging (no change in hospitalization and down-stream increases in ED use). But what about cost? That’s what the new study is about.

    The new work uses the same data, so let’s review from my prior post.

    [It] spanned four years, 2007-2010. [It] also exploits the natural experiment of one, large, midwestern manufacturer that fully replaced its PPO with a CDHP + HSA option (consumer directed health plan + health savings account). Except for voluntary switches to plans outside the employer (e.g., spousal coverage or by leaving the employer altogether), this eliminates selection bias among plan enrollees. If an employee wanted coverage from this employer, she had to switch to the CDHP.

    Still, this is not a randomized trial. The authors selected a matched comparison group from another, similar employer and obtained a very close match on age and other demographics, comborbidities, and prior use of health care services. There were 10,509 subjects in each of the CDHP and comparison groups.

    Two CDHP + HSA options were offered at the plan-switching employer. They differed in level of annual deductible ($1,250 vs. $2,150 for an individual and $2,150 vs. $4,300 for a family), employee premium contribution ($271 vs. $0 for an individual and $2,184 vs. $1,417 for a family). Employer HSA contributions were the same for both plans ($700 for an individual and $1,300 for a family). Almost 90% of employees chose the higher deductible/lower premium option.

    The following chart shows total spending for CDHP enrollees and the comparison group. It begins in 2006, which is the year before the switch to CDHP. That’s the baseline year. Since, as is evident, those who ended up in a CDHP collectively spent less than the comparison group in the baseline year, you need to measure all spending differences between the CDHP and comparison groups relative to that baseline. This is a difference-in-differences set-up.

    CDHP vs comparison

    It’s pretty clear that from the baseline year (2006) to 2007, spending for the CDHP (or HSA, as the legend says) group grew much less than for the comparison group. In fact, the difference-in-difference estimate is that the CDHP group’s spending growth was 25% below that of the comparison group’s. However, after the first year, the growth difference moderates. With a model that controls for demographics, geographic region, and health status, the investigators found that, relative to 2006 levels, CDHP growth is only 8%, 4%, and 6% below that of the comparison group’s in 2008, 2009, and 2010, respectively.

    Why such a big change from year one to the following years? The authors suggest this is due to experience over time with the new CDHP plan.

    Health insurance coverage is complex for non-health maintenance organization (non-HMO) plans because their premiums do not account for nearly all of the spending by plan participants, as they do in HMOs. In plans with choices of providers, health insurance coverage is laden with multiple cost-sharing mechanisms within the same plan; differential cost for high-performance vs. standard networks of providers; in-network vs. out-of-network cost sharing; reference pricing (fixed payments for services with beneficiaries paying the difference for any higher charges); and tiered pharmacy payments where the placement of a medication in a tier is associated with a different beneficiary cost. The addition of a large deductible and an account with employer-provided funds to this mix certainly increases the cognitive demands for new users of account-based, high-deductible health plans. However, it is reasonable to expect that behaviors will change as users become more familiar with how to use the plan for meeting health-care-services needs over time.

    I have another potential explanation: Perhaps in year 1, CDHP enrollees tried relatively harder to forgo care, saving their money under the deductible for only things that seemed urgent. However, what they may have done is actually put off care they needed and in subsequent years there was a relief of this self-imposed, pent-up demand.

    In any case, no matter the explanation, this study suggests that CDHPs offer savings. But, long-term, those savings are relatively modest. They’re no where near enough to fully offset the exorbitant amount spent on health care in the U.S., relative to other, wealthy countries. That is, CDHPs may be part of a solution, but they are not by themselves a full solution.

    The paper is ungated and there’s more in it than I’ve written about above.

    @afrakt

    Share
    Comments closed
     
    • It is common knowledge that larger deductibles mean lower premiums.
      One of the problems with HSAs is that the balance is not directly linked to the deductible, thus increasing a funded deductible for a lower premium.
      Another drawback is that HSAs are seen by many as a way to pay for health care costs each year. The average balance in an HSA is something like $1,500.
      We need a different type of HSA. A type of account which grows faster than the piddly interest rates. An account which does not provide cash, but which provides paid-up benefits to fund an ever increasing deductible and ever-reducing premiums (as long as claims are not made). Instead of accumulating piddly amounts of cash to pay piddly insurance claims, one accumulate $25,000 of paid-up benefits over 3 years, by paying $300 a month.
      That will raise your funded deductible to $25,000 and save 60% off your premiums, every year!
      Don Levit.
      Don Levit

    • Austin
      I searched in the paper for HR support within new plan. No mention.

      We will see a flurry of papers such as these the next few years with increased popularity in CDHPs. However, you have seen one CDHP– and you have seen one CDHP. Perhaps.

      You recall, the recent RAND paper demonstrated decreases in covered preventive services with HSA uptake. Why? Plausible? I would not have guessed.

      Given the experiment played out in one town, in one company, good stewardship of the plan (online tools and human contact/advice) as source for better performance not unrealistic.

      Perhaps folks had some help navigating from within, assisting in their choices..

      Brad

    • Again, we have evidence that giving consumers the “choice” to spend less by increasing their costs leads to them foregoing necessary medical care.
      Cost of care is a big problem but encouraging people to go without necessary care is shortsighted. We need to lower the cost of care (overpriced services and overused services of dubious value). Overpriced services are easy to find but politically hard to fix. Overused services of dubious value cannot reliably be identified by consumers who do not have the knowledge to discern the difference between necessary and unnecessary care. The medical profession must step up to the plate on this issue.

    • Mark:
      I agree with you that we need to lower the cost of care, both overpriced and overused services.
      Without lowering the cost of care, any other positive changes we make to the mix are severely curtailed.
      When you write that giving consumers the choice to spend less by increasing their costs, leads to foregoing necessary medical care, this presents a huge obstacle to lowering costs.
      Particularly for smaller claims, if many people are unable to pay $100, $200, $500, or even $1,000 of expenses, how are we going to be able to effectively cover the cost of much larger (and more appropriate) insurable expenses)?
      When we provide low or no deductibles so that people can afford medical services, from an insurance standpoint, we are “trading dollars” with the insurance company. Insurers love low deductibles, for they come out way ahead in the trading of dollars at these levels.
      Pretty much everyone knows that the higher deductible, the lower the premium.
      We are at a point where even the premiums are too pricey for most families – thus the need for subsidies.
      If we have to subsidize the premiums and the cost of smaller expenses, how are we ever going to be able to obtain the important objective you cited of lowering overall costs?
      Don Levit

    • One important point to mention about the potential downstream effects of CDHPs on provider prices: as more patients choose lower-priced providers, higher-priced providers will be forced to lower their prices to regain market share. Thus, CDHPs could actually make a huge difference in total spending, but it would be on the prices side rather than the utilization side.

      No evidence exists (that I can find) that says what percent of patients need to be making decisions like this before prices will actually start dropping.

      This argument also includes all the standard assumptions about patients being able to find out prices beforehand, etc.